G. K. Helleiner, University of Toronto Department of Economics
October 15, 1997New York- I have been asked to speak to you on the subject of the twice-postponed UN conference on the financing of development. I believe this to be a potentially import it initiative- one which the whole world could be watching. And I am happy to be able to be able to trade some ideas on it with you.
Let me begin however, with some contextual caution. (Perhaps it is the professional caution of a dismal scientist.) The world of human exchange, whether national or international-the world of trade and finance and the exchange of knowledge -has a life of its own. Exchange takes place through a vast variety of institutions- markets (competitive, oligopolistic, monopolistic, etc.); and various non-market hierarchical arrangements in firms and families and bureaucracies. Its nature and consequences are greatly influenced by institutions, customs, laws and traditions. All of this exchange (and the institutions through which it is mediated) has -a major impact upon incomes income distribution and development, both nationally and internationally. Human welfare is also enormously affected by previous history (what some call "initial conditions") and by random shocks-weather, ocean currents, volcanic eruptions, price changes engendered by impersonal interactions on markets, and the like. It is also, of course, affected by such important human activities as violence to one another (individual or collective), technical change and social/political/institutional evolution or decay. All of these influences upon human welfare and development are operative with or without the existence of nation-states, governments or international organizations. These various market and non-market forces are typically far more important in the overall scheme of global development than, with all due respect, the labors and strainings of statesmen and diplomats (and academics). One must therefore always retain due modesty about what policymakers can do for development.
The past half-century has seen tumultuous change, much of it the product of "spontaneous" influences, in the world economy. In no sphere has this change beet, greater, particularly in the last quarter-century, than in international finance. In very large part, the emergence of globalized financial markets was the product of technical change in information processing, telecommunications and transport. But. that said, conscious governmental actions-in the general direction of market liberalization- have also played some role.
Whatever the cause, private capital now dominates the total net (long-term) financial flows to the developing world -- as much as 85% of the total in 1996. (This compares with around 45% in 1990 and much less in the 1950s and 1960s.) Portfolio flows in globalized financial markets make up over 40% of current private flows to the developing world. Pension funds, mutual funds and life insurance companies, investing in bonds and equities, are now considerably more significant sources of development finance than banks (whose activities peaked, to disastrous effect, in the late 1970s and early 1980s). Foreign direct investment is also rapidly rising again (and now accounts for about 45% of total private flows; it made up 55% in 1990 and much larger percentages in the 1950s and 1960s). [All of these data are from the World Bank's Global Development Finance, 1997. ] At the same time the world has been experiencing the so-called "crisis of aid": official flows are stagnant or declining except from a small number of donor countries (the Nordics and the Dutch).
Unfortunately as is well known private flows are highly concentrated in a relatively few countries. According to the World Bank, 95% of the flows to developing countries in 1996 went to just 26 countries; 140 countries shared the remaining 5%. Worse still, private capital has proven highly fickle and volatile in its behavior: portfolio managers have proven just as nervous in the 1990s as banks were in the 1970s and 1980s. And transnational corporations managing their own portfolios have emerged as major movers of short-term funds. It is not necessary to demonize George Soros or other money managers, who are merely trying to protect their shareholders' interests in a highly uncertain world. It is simply in the nature of financial markets. that they are susceptible to panics, crises and volatility.
Governments can and do play some role both in the evolution of the global financial system and in the determination of its effects upon development in individual countries. At the national level, all governments have a particular responsibility for the stability and security of the domestic monetary, banking and financial systems -- critically important to the functioning of any economy. The vulnerability of banking and financial systems to crises, instability and market failure has virtually everywhere produced central banks and regulatory authorities to protect the social interest and, usually, to mediate national interactions with global financial markets. Effective functioning and stability of the monetary and financial system is now universally seen as a fundamental requisite for development; and it can only be achieved through effective state action. The ultimate responsibility for national level development -- including macroeconomic management, the encouragement and effective deployment of savings and investment, and modes of interaction with the global economy-always rests with national governments. Their record is clear -- that, whatever their other characteristics, developmental policies are most effective when they are truly locally designed, implemented and monitored.
But who plays the role of the development-oriented state in the global economy? Effective global macroeconomic and financial management is far more important to overall output, employment, and development than any individual national-level actions or, for that matter, any changes in the trade regime. Exchange rate changes and misalignments can and do easily swamp trade policies in the short- to medium-run. Financial crises and surges in private capital markets can disrupt the global economy far more quickly and to far greater effect than any trade phenomena. It is therefore critically important to get the central macroeconomic financial institutions for the newly globalized economy broadly right. Today's global financial world, the world in which governmental promote development, at both the national and international levels is utterly different from that facing the original architects of the Bretton Woods system in 1944, a time when the international financial markets had, in effect, been closed down.
The central governmental institutions in today's global economy are those of the major industrial powers and, intergovernmentally, the meetings of the G-7, realistically the G-3, (Finance Ministers or Heads of State), the International Monetary Fund, the World Bank, and the Bank for International Settlements, and all of their committees. All have been attempting to come to terms with some of the monumental changes in the global financial system of the past couple of decades. Finance ministers and central bankers, in pursuit of safety and stability (not development per se), have been trying valiantly to develop appropriate governance arrangements to "catch up" with global financial market forces.
Unfortunately, the process through which the current international monetary and financial system is attempting to respond to the challenges thrown up by the new global economy is severely flawed. It is tortuously slow, insufficiently participatory, overly influenced by powerful lobbies from the financial sector, and constrained by jurisdictional ambiguities and turf struggles. It is difficult at present to be very sanguine about the early prospects for appropriate changes -- particularly those likely to assist processes of development in the developing world-that emanate from the current efforts of such bodies the G-7, the BIS, the IMF, the World Bank, the various regional development banks, or, for that matter, the WTO, the OECD or such non-governmental organizations as the International Chamber of Commerce. I shall be saying more about this in a minute.
Above all, the process is flawed because of its failure to take adequately into account another element of major change within the global economy and the global financial system, a change which has been of fundamental importance-and is much less remarked upon in the dominant financial institutions. That is the rapidly growing importance of non-G7 members in the world economy. and therefore the growing importance of these economies to G-7 and global welfare. I am speaking not so much about population trends as about basic economic strength and economic potential. In purchasing power parity terms, developing countries alone already account for nearly half of world output. According to the World Bank, by the year 2010 they will account for 56% of global consumption and 57% of global capital formation. And developing countries as a group are still generally projected to grow at roughly double the rate of-the industrial world during the coming decade.
We have recently been reminded, first in Mexico and now in Southeast Asia, that there is another important dimension to increasing developing-country participation in the global economy and global financial markets. Developing countries' economic performance is subject to much greater volatility than that of the more industrialized countries. The closer integration of the developing and transition countries into the world economy and their greater importance to it pose increased risks -- not only to themselves but also to the entire global system. There are bound to be many more Mexican-style and Southeast Asian-style crises in the years to come. Developing countries have also recently proven more prone to disasters of climate, civil disturbance and war.
Apart from the fact that the G-7 countries represent a small and declining proportion of the world's population, their own economic and political security now rests significantly and increasingly upon events in the rest of the world. From these facts flows-an inescapable conclusion: the world must find a way not only towards improved management of a newly globalized economic system-a difficult enough task-but also toward more politically and economically representative, and therefore more legitimate and more effective, means of global economic governance. And the search for such reformed arrangements must begin in the world of global finance, where the risks are highest and the potential gains from
The problems of the international financial system and its interaction with the agreed objective of global development are all of a single piece. It would be nonsensical to attempt to address the issues surrounding the future of the financing of development in isolation from the many influences upon the now-dominant private flows of capital. Such influences include the macroeconomic policies of the major industrial countries, particularly as they affect interest rates; the provision of adequate liquidity and appropriate responses to periodic crises; the backstopping and supervisory roles of the major international financial institutions-not only the IMF and World Bank group but also the regional development banks, the BIS and related institutions. If there is to be a useful conference on the financing of development, it must therefore address the workings of the entire international monetary and financial system as it impacts upon development. A conference, if there is to be one, should be about "the international monetary and financial system and development." No less will do. (The developmental focus is essential, if only to discourage endless further debate on the appropriate exchange rate arrangements among the US dollar, the emerging Euro and the yen-the issue which, under Northern influences, ran away with far too much of the discussion on the occasion of the fiftieth anniversary of the Bretton Woods institutions.)
Some urge the United Nations to stay out of monetary and financial affairs. One can certainly make a case that, in the interest of an efficient international division of labour, monetary and financial issues should be raised and addressed in the appropriate multilateral fora --presumably, at present, the International Monetary Fund and the World Bank group. Most Finance Ministers and Central Banks do not regard the UN as an appropriate forum for discussion of these matters. Most probably do not know or, if they know, do not much care that the Second Committee is debating them this week in New York. From their standpoint, the only meetings that truly mattered were those in Hong Kong a month ago, meetings that they all attended.
Let us be clear about these matters: the IMF and the World Bank group have done much of their work extremely well, better than quite a lot of the work undertaken by other specialized agencies of the UN, and one must never minimize the difficult of achieving effective international governmental cooperation in any sphere, let alone in the complex world of international money and finance. We can and should celebrate the remarkable successes of the IMF, the World Bank Group, the regional development banks and the rest -- and many of us have done so. But let us also be clear that they have done their work relatively well principally because they were financially supported to do it well. The administrative budgets of the IMF and the World Bank -- totaling roughly two billion dollars per year -- are considerably larger than the combined administrative budget of all of the rest of the UN system with all of its other responsibilities. The question of the cost-effectiveness of these expenditures in the Bretton Woods institutions, in support of multilateral economic and financial governance, is rarely raised. (To take a small current example- the World Bank's World Development Report is reliably estimated to have cost roughly four million dollars, far more than the UN system spent upon its World Economic Survey, Trade and Development Report and Human Development Report combined.) The question is: are the current international financial institutions likely to be" able to transform themselves, spontaneously and without prodding and in a reasonable time frame, into what will be required for the emerging world of the twenty-first century?
The primary concerns of the majority of the world's countries have repeatedly been raised within the existing multilateral monetary and financial institutions: in particular, the effective introduction of global considerations into G-7 macroeconomic management fora; the provision of liquidity in true accordance with global need; more effective response to sovereign bankruptcy, and debt and financial crises- the regularization of development finance; more effective and representative governance in these institutions themselves; and developing-country representation in financial supervisory and regulatory-provisions for the global financial community.
Perhaps the developing (and transition) countries have not tried hard enough within the existing institutional machinery. Perhaps their spokesmen and women, and their representatives on the relevant boards, have been too junior in their levels, or too timid in their efforts. Perhaps developing-country Finance Ministers should assign higher priority than they now do to these multilateral economic governance issues (although their frequent inability and/or unwillingness to do so is perfectly understandable for smaller and poorer countries). Perhaps the G-24 could run its affairs much more effectively. All of these could be done. But would it, under current arrangements, make much difference? I suspect not much.
Consider some of the recent evidence. Recent efforts to amend the articles of the IMF centered on (i) an "equity" allocation of SDRS, rather than an allocation to meet global needs as perceived by the majority of its members, and (ii) an expanded mandate to permit it to push the liberalization of private international capital flows with greater vigour -- hardly the top priority reform for the majority of its members either. Whose priorities were these? At the same time, the recent expansion of IMF quotas made virtually zero concession to the growing importance and needs of developing countries. The most the Managing Director could do was to offer. in return for developing-country support for the much-needed current quota expansion, to look at these matters next time. These are not signs of an organization able easily to recast itself in the interest of the majority of its members. They are, rather, stark reminders of who still really runs the principal global monetary institution.
Again, without casting any aspersions on the qualities of the current office-holders, it is worth asking-in the context of all of the current "buzz" about governance in their Institutions' boards-how the positions of President of the World Bank and Managing Director of the IMF, with all of their considerable attendant powers, are at present filled? What exactly are the transparent and participatory and rules-based procedures, which the World Bank recommends for all, through which these major multilateral leaders of the financial community are selected? The bizarre and hilarious manner in which the next-to-last President of the World Bank was appointed is recounted in the brilliant, new-released history of the World Bank by Devesh Kapur, John Lewis and Richard Webb [The World Bank, the First Half Century, Volume 1, History (Brookings Institution, Washington,. DC, 1997), page 1199]. Who can take seriously the World Bank's strictures on others' governance when its own governance is so severely flawed?
The reforms being pursued in the sphere of international banking supervision by the BIS and the regulation of international securities markets by IOSCO are, of course, welcome and overdue. But the BIS, a central bank for G-10 central bankers, is even less representative of global interests than the IMF; and IOSCO is even less so. Both deserve credit for recently consulting with developing countries. But is this enough? (Incidentally, neither are answerable to elected representatives in their own countries.)
There is an overwhelming intellectual case for a strengthened multilateral framework both for the conduct of international global finance and for sound global macroeconomic governance in the interest of both stability and development. But one cannot, in good conscience, continue to recommend the strengthening of the roles of the IMF and World Bank in global macroeconomic management and the management of financial system (as I have myself done in the past) as long as their own governance has not been reconstituted so as to reflect more accurately and fairly their global membership. Much as they try to convey a more attractive image to the world, they still disproportionately reflect in their actions and policies the views and interests of a few major industrial countries.
Developed countries have utterly different voting powers and the provisions for special majorities for particular categories of decision vary enormously from one international economic organization to another. Comparing the governance structures of a large number of multilateral organizations, the INIF. and World Bank place last in their representativeness of the majority of the world's countries and peoples. Developed countries (as defined by the World. Bank) account for 17% of overall votes in the Global Environmental Facility (the same as in the UN itself), 24% in the WTO, 34% in the IFAD, 48% in the IDB, 60% in the ADB, and 61-62% in the World Bank and INV. [Ngaire Woods, "Governance in International Organizations: The Case for Reform in the Bretton Woods Institutions", forthcoming in International Monetary and Financial Issues for the 1990s, Vol. IX (United Nations).]
Financial strength should not grant the degree of cross-the-board institutional and political power currently enjoyed in the international financial institutions by the G-7 governmental oligopoly. No doubt financial contributions bring some extra rights. (They also bring extra responsibilities.) Political democracy and the rule of law have been based, however, on quite different principles (granted that they have frequently been abused in practice).
Let me be more direct and extend the argument: brain power and technical insight have' never been correlated strongly with the amount of money people-bring to the table. Not the least of the changes in the global village of the past few decades has been the ascendancy of a whole new generation of Southern technocrats and academics with an interest in and capacity for sophisticated analysis of global issues. particularly as they affect development. There is simply no remaining rational basis for the continuing degree of reliance, on the part of the IMF and World Bank, upon North American and European scholars and consultants. (For instance, in a recent conference on the future of the SDR, I counted only nine developing- or transition-country speakers out of a total of 36 on the program. Of eight more participants listed in the subsequent publication as having participated in the general discussion, only one was from a developing country. These proportions are fairly typical.)
There are now more staff-members from developing countries within these institutions than there once were. Staff-members of such organizations are always severely constrained, however, in their activities. In-house analyses and evaluations can rarely generate much self-criticism or results that stray seriously from the current "policy line". Bureaucratic incentives simply do not encourage such independence of mind. Change and fresh thinking is sometimes pushed "from the top" as once again at present in the World Bank, but rarely to very much long-term effect.
Pressure for more significant change usually comes from- elsewhere; from bad experience or -- but this may be more difficult-from truly independent external assessments and recommendations, particularly when buttressed by some significant political or intellectual authority. Further bad experience will surely assist the process of change; but one can hardly recommend further financial crises. On the other hand, one can and should try to breathe more "fresh air" into the currently somewhat inbred discussions of global money, finance, and development in the Bretton Woods institutions.
I hope I have made it clear that, because the needs of the entire global community are at stake, and because the existing international financial institutions are so unrepresentative and show so little sign of making necessary changes in the near future, I believe that the Second Committee of the United Nations General Assembly now has little alternative but to take a keen interest in the current state of multilateral governance in monetary and financial matters, particularly as they affect development.
But how can it move events forwards? How do we all get from here to there? There are many possible options, only one of which is a global conference. There should certainly be no expectation that, as at Bretton Woods, one extended meeting can deal with all of the problems One should instead be thinking in terms of a more effective process of change -- change which is urgently needed but seems very slow in coming. The aims are both to improve the final product and to speed the progress toward it. However one proceeds (and a final word about that in a minute), a useful starting point -- or a point quite early in a new process -- would be a global conference. It could serve an important educative and galvanizing purpose. It must not serve, as conferences sometimes do, as a de facto substitute for action.
What realistic options for an improved process might be considered? Let me offer four -- and they are not necessarily mutually exclusive.
The Secretary-General of the UN might appoint a panel of independent and representative experts to address the major questions, and to make recommendations. To do this, he would no doubt want to consult with the Bretton Woods institutions; but he must not be dependent upon them. Such commissions may not seem to change the world so much. But they can be important elements in a process of review, popularization of important ideas, and change. In retrospect, the Pearson, Brandt and Brundtland Commissions were important signals of such change in the second half of the twentieth century.
As earlier recommended by the Group of 24, one could seek to re-initiate an intergovernmental process like that of the Committee of Twenty, created by the Bretton Woods institutions themselves in the 1970s, to reconsider their functioning in the new financial world of that decade. (The twenty were equally divided between industrial and developing countries.) In the absence of IMF/Bank response to this request, such a prospect would have to be initiated from elsewhere, and might be more difficult to launch. It might usefully be discussed in the Second Committee. [For details as to how it worked and might again work, see Aziz Ali F. Mohammed, "Global Financial System Reform and the C-20 Process", International Monetary and Financial Issues for the 1990s, Vol. VII (United Nations).]
Separate reviews might be initiated at the regional level; perhaps by the regional economic commissions of the United Nations (or perhaps by the regional development banks), and perhaps all under the Secretary-General's or ECOSOC's umbrella authority. Proposals from Japan and Australia for regional IMF-style, funds and improved arrangements for increased regional monetary cooperation in Asia suggest that some such thinking is already under way; and it needs to be placed appropriately into a more global context.
Some developing countries and/or some industrial "middle powers" might initiate their own independent or intergovernmental review the recommendations, as has previously been done in other dimensions of UN activity. These possibilities might be actively explored in the forthcoming Extraordinary Meeting of G-24 Ministers of Finance.
No doubt there are many other possibilities. I hope you will consider many such possible avenues for broader progress in the sphere of global economic governance as you debate the merits of the proposed conference on the financing of development. On behalf of all of those with a concern for effective global economic governance and for development, let me wish you every success in your deliberations.
More Information on Financing for Development
FAIR USE NOTICE: This page contains copyrighted material the use of which has not been specifically authorized by the copyright owner. Global Policy Forum distributes this material without profit to those who have expressed a prior interest in receiving the included information for research and educational purposes. We believe this constitutes a fair use of any such copyrighted material as provided for in 17 U.S.C íŸ 107. If you wish to use copyrighted material from this site for purposes of your own that go beyond fair use, you must obtain permission from the copyright owner.